Japan in the Post–3/11 Era: The Road to Rebirth

Earthquakes and the Economy

Politics Society

Takemori Shunpei [Profile]

The question on many minds today is what economic ramifications the March 11 earthquake and tsunami will have. This article explores this issue by looking back on the major earthquake the country experienced in 1923 and again in 1995, and considering the impact of those earlier disasters on Japan’s economy.

Contribution to the Economic Recovery


A view of the apartment buildings that line the new residential area that sprang up around Kobe’s port after the 1995 earthquake.

What sort of impact did the Kobe earthquake have on the Japanese economy as a whole? The Great Hanshin-Awaji Earthquake occurred on January 17, 1995, and in the January–March quarter of that year the growth rate of Japan’s real GDP, while remaining positive, fell to a low figure of 0.2% (annualized), presumably reflecting the impact of the quake. But in the following two quarters, April–June and July–September, the economy grew at a rate of 1.3%, and in the final quarter, October–December, the rate climbed to 2.3%. This brought the growth rate for the entire year to 1.4%. This was a substantial increase over the previous year’s growth rate of 0.6%; not only that, but it was the highest rate since 1990, when Japan’s stock market bubble burst. The yen was extremely strong in 1995, trading at a rate of ¥79 to the dollar, which made conditions difficult for exporters, and so the strength of the economy’s growth this year is all the more remarkable.

To judge from these figures, the Kobe earthquake seems not to have acted as a drag on the Japanese economy in 1995; on the contrary, there is a strong chance that the resulting reconstruction demand helped power the economic recovery. We can hypothesize a number of reasons for the fact that the earthquake did not weigh the economy down.

First we should note that as of January 1995 the Japanese economy was in a period of stagnation following the collapse of the bubbles that formed in the late 1980s. The stock market peaked in the second half of 1989, and the real estate market in the second half of 1991, but even after the stock and real estate bubbles burst in 1990 and 1992, respectively, many commentators in the Japanese media maintained that the consumption boom would continue. In fact, however, the collapse in the value of real estate—which at one point was so high that it was said the grounds of the Imperial Palace in Tokyo could be assessed at a price worth twice the value of all the land in California—resulted in the failure of many investments that were predicated on ongoing increases in land prices. The companies that made these investments were stuck with huge liabilities, and the banks that lent money for the investments found themselves with huge piles of nonperforming loans. This widespread debt burden was something that Japan had never experienced before in the post–World War II period.

“The economy will pick up this year.” That was the refrain each year through 1994. Given the combination of falling asset prices, ballooning debt, and a business downturn, the monetary policy authorities naturally had to move toward a looser stance. I used to accept the conventional evaluation that the Bank of Japan hesitated to lower interest rates lest the bubbles reemerge. This perception ties in with the famous remark made in 1992 by Kanemaru Shin, the powerful politician then serving as vice-president of the ruling Liberal Democratic Party, who declared that the discount rate should be cut, even if it meant firing the governor of the BOJ.

It is true that the central bank was slow to lower its discount rate, but it actually moved quite rapidly to lower what is now referred to as its policy interest rate, namely, the overnight call rate. As I now see it, the reason this loosening was not very effective either in helping financial institutions’ performance or in giving a boost to the economy as a whole is that the bank had been attempting to rein in the speculative frenzy by pushing the overnight rate up to an excessively high level until just before the bursting of the bubbles. Since this short-term interest rate was so high, even the rapid moves to lower it were not sufficient to bring it down to a level low enough to stimulate investment.

Putting Idle Equipment into Operation

Before the Kobe earthquake the Japanese economy was in the doldrums, and so there was idle equipment at enterprises around the country. This is an important point to note when considering what happened to the economy after the quake.

Even if it is possible to use increased inputs of labor as a substitute for other factors of production, if an economy is in good shape, with plant and equipment operating steadily, then the loss of productive capital stock due to a major disaster will lead to a decline in production, thereby acting as a drag on GDP. As of the beginning of 1995, however, there was a considerable amount of idle equipment in Japan as a whole. It was quite possible to make up for the production capacity lost in Kobe by bringing this idle equipment back into operation. And that is not all. The reactivation of this equipment had a further positive effect on the Japanese economy, which was caught in a postbubble slowdown.

The existence of idle capital equipment itself is a source of economic stagnation. An economy cannot grow without vigorous investment, but the presence of idle equipment makes businesses reluctant to invest in new equipment, which would aggravate the excess in production capacity. On top of that, firms with excess equipment are liable to produce goods just for the sake of keeping the equipment in operation and sell the resulting products for any price they can get. This fosters a deflationary trend in prices, which in turn makes it difficult to recoup the cost of new equipment through sales of the products made with this equipment. So businesses become even more reluctant to invest. At the beginning of 1995, the Japanese economy had fallen into this sort of persistent slump in investment sentiment.

The situation changed dramatically with the January 17 earthquake, which destroyed capital equipment in Kobe and led to higher rates of capacity utilization in other parts of the country. Businesses became bullish about investing in new equipment. One element of this was the appetite for investment in equipment to replace what had been lost in the quake. As I noted above, firms did not simply replace the old machinery but installed the latest models. So in some cases they ended up with higher production capacity than before. The second element was the nationwide increase in capacity utilization, which caused businesses to think positively about investing in additional equipment. The earthquake helped alleviate the excess in production capacity that up to then had been acting as the biggest impediment to investment.

It is easy to see how the above two elements pushing up investment may have been the cause of the 1995 growth rate, which was higher than in any previous year since the bursting of the bubbles. Horwich suggests that the effects of the BOJ’s monetary policy relaxation from 1992 on made themselves felt in a time-lagged manner at this point. When the BOJ seeks to lower short-term interest rates, it buys securities on the open market and thereby ensures that there is ample money in circulation. But no matter how ample the supply of funds may be, if businesses are not interested in using this money to expand their investments, the easing will have little effect in stimulating the economy.

The situation up to the beginning of 1995 was precisely of this nature. Businesses had large amounts of excess equipment and felt little inclination to take advantage of the available funds. But when firms’ desire to invest surged following the earthquake, the ample supply of money made it easy for them to borrow the funds needed for their investments. So they were able to follow through on their bullish plans to add new equipment.

next: Fast Forward to 2011

Related Tags

Great East Japan Earthquake Great Kantō Earthquake Great Hanshin-Awaji Earthquake Bank of Japan

Takemori ShunpeiView article list

Senior researcher at the Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry, chair of Mitsubishi UFJ Research and Consulting, member of a committee set up to advise the Japanese government on Basic Policies for Novel Coronavirus Disease Control, and private-sector delegate to the Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy. Born in Tokyo in 1956. Graduated from Keiō University in 1981, where he majored in economics. After completing his doctoral studies at Keiō in 1986, received his PhD in economics from the University of Rochester in 1989. Has been an associate professor at Keiō. Author of Keizai kiki wa kokonotsu no kao o motsu (Economic Crisis Has Nine Faces), Sekai o kaeta kin’yū kiki (The Financial Crisis That Has Changed the World), Keizai ronsen wa yomigaeru (The Revival of Economic Debate; winner of the Yomiuri–Yoshino Sakuzō Prize), and other works.

Other articles in this report