Why Are Wages Not Rising Despite the Labor Shortage?

Economy

According to standard economic theory, a shortage of workers will cause wages to rise. Why is this not happening in Japan? Is it because of insufficient capital investment, as the government suggests? Other factors may be more important, notably the weakness of companies’ on-the-job training. And given the rigidity of regular wages, greater flexibility in bonus payments seems like a better route to higher pay.

The Lingering Effects of the Employment Ice Age

The decline in the development of workers’ abilities is especially pronounced among those in their late thirties to early forties, who graduated during the so-called employment ice age. The salaries of university graduates in their early forties are substantially lower (on average, ¥23,000 less) than those of their seniors hired during the go-go years of the bubble economy. Job hopping became a common practice among the graduates hired during the employment ice age, meaning that their years of service with their current employers tend to be lower than those of their stay-put seniors. Also, the numbers of graduates taking jobs with small or medium-sized enterprises increased during the ice age. Both of these changes have tended to hold down their wage levels. On top of that, many say that they did not have sufficient opportunity to develop their abilities when they were in their twenties. In other words, the decline of on-the-job training dating back to the employment ice age is continuing to put dampers on the wages of those in the prime of their working lives.

Another point we must consider in relation to the impact of capital investment on wages is the content of the investment. The government has noted that labor productivity is lower than it was in the 1990s, but that was a decade when computers and information technology were coming into wide use in workplaces. In the case of the United States, the introduction of new technology led to a sharp widening of the income gap between “winners”—highly skilled people able to deal with this new technology, whose wages rose substantially—and “losers”—people short of skills and ill equipped to adjust to the technological advances, whose wages went down.

The technological innovations introduced through capital investment now and in the years to come are liable to produce only a tiny minority of winners and turn the large majority of employees into losers. Investments will be directed toward full-scale introduction of artificial intelligence and robots into workplaces. The minority of employees whose abilities have been developed sufficiently for them to make full use of AI and robots will earn high salaries, but the remaining majority will have to seek employment opportunities in other fields or take lower-paying jobs. So capital investment, rather than raising wage levels, may well actually push them down further.

The Downward Rigidity of Wages

As set forth above, I am doubtful about the scenario of increased capital investment leading to higher wages. It seems to me that we are more likely to find the clue to raising wages by looking at the structure of the labor market.

The book I mentioned above consists of 16 chapters, four of which deal with the close connection between downward wage rigidity and upward wage rigidity. It is known both in Japan and elsewhere that workers resent wage cuts and that such cuts have a negative impact on their motivation. Conversely, as long as their wages hold steady, they tend not to be that insistent on pay raises.

Suppose an enterprise considers raising wages in response to the current labor shortage. Given the high level of uncertainty about the future, the enterprise cannot exclude the possibility that deterioration of its business performance at some point will put pressure on it to cut back on personnel expenses. But once wages have been hiked, it will be hard to reduce them. The enterprise may as a result find its very survival in jeopardy. This is why employers hesitate to raise wages even when labor is in short supply. The book also refers to data indicating that enterprises that have never cut wages over the past 10 years have not raised them either, while those that have repeatedly cut wages have also been positive about raising them.

If workers’ psychology limits the scope for changes in wage levels, it becomes all the more difficult to envisage wage hikes being achieved through fiscal and monetary policy measures.

Aiming for Higher Bonuses

So is there no way of getting wages to rise? If companies want to respond to the labor shortage and to increase the motivation levels of their employees, their first step should be to increase bonuses, even if only temporarily, while holding monthly pay steady. Though workers resist cuts in their monthly pay, this attitude does not apply to bonuses. So companies should use bonuses as a tool for adjusting their personnel expenses, cutting them when necessary to cope with a downturn in business results.

The process of negotiating bonus levels will give the labor market a mechanism for adjusting annual pay levels in response to shifts in labor market supply and demand. Back when labor unions were powerful, bonus levels used to be set more flexibly from year to year on the basis of labor-management agreements. This has been cited as the reason for Japan’s success in keeping its unemployment rate low.

According to a survey by the daily Nikkei, this year’s summer bonuses in the nonmanufacturing sector, where the labor shortage is severe, are 5.5% higher than last year. It is the first time in 27 years that this figure has risen by more than 5%. Workers should push for even bigger hikes in this winter’s bonuses.

Japanese workers are altogether too complacent regarding their own compensation. Pay hikes do not emerge naturally through the operation of an invisible hand. The question is whether workers will be able to act with solidarity to make their voices heard.

(Originally published in Japanese on August 2, 2017.Banner photo: Representative members of the Federation of All Toyota Workers’ Unions participate in a rally on March 9, 2017, in Toyoda, Aichi Prefecture, toward the end of this year’s spring round of labor-management negotiations. © Jiji.)

Related Tags

employment labor wage

Other articles in this report